LENIN'S TOMB

 

Sunday, January 02, 2005

The Protestant Ethic. posted by Richard Seymour

I've always been interested in Weber's assertion of a causal connection between the rise of puritan values and the rise of capitalism. In many ways, I had thought that the relationship was rather the opposite that he had stipulated: that the new middle class, the burghers and tradesmen who were already forming a capitalist society simply happened to be drawn toward a certain kind of Protestantism. On the other hand, was it not the aristocratic class which had enabled capitalism through its enclosures of the land, forcing peasants out into the towns where they would both form the labour market and a market for consumption? Things become even more tricky when you look at how Weber draws out the connections he claims exist. He seems, at times, to proffer a stronger thesis (that capitalism could only have come into existence with the unique X-factor of puritanism) than is justified by the evidence he cites; at others, he seems merely to say that the two are connected. For a theorist so profound and exact in the development of his concepts, this is extraordinary. What follows is a rough sketch of Weber's thesis, drawing on the original text and a few cricitical or corroboratory works by other authors. Now, you and I both know there's nothing good on telly, so go ahead and give it a once-over.

"Elective affinity"


Weber’s thesis, in The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism (TPESC), is approximately thus: The rise of capitalism in the West is part of its uniqueness, the unique result of an “elective affinity” between the needs of capitalist production and the discipline of the Lutheran ‘calling’. (Weber, TPESC, chapter 3, 1930). There are two contradictory motives involved in capitalist production: 1) Amass wealth beyond personal need, and 2) Avoid the use of wealth to satisfy personal desire. These motives cohabit well with the demands of Protestantism that the believer devote herself to a life of good works, and the Puritan devotion to asceticism. (Ken Morrison, Marx, Durkheim, Weber: Formations of Modern Social Thought, 1995).

Weber’s approach to capitalism is significant for this thesis in a number of ways. First of all, he believed that capitalism was contrary to human nature, a freak occurrence that arose from the conjugation of a number of historical events and epochs, starting with the Greco-Roman city-states. This reflected a commitment to methodological individualism, his opposition to Marxist models which saw history as an ordered procession of stages (modes of production) which were universal. According to Weber, there is no order in history and its stages are unique rather than universal. Weber is interested in locating the general tendencies in history, but he is also alert to the importance of local variations and differences. He seeks to avoid a “one-sided materialistic” view of history, and therefore attempts to conjoin analysis of the material with the spiritual – that is, between patterns of belief and systems of social action. (Bryan S. Turner, Max Weber: From History to Modernity, 1992; Morrison, 1995). Weber contrasts Western capitalism to ‘Oriental’ civilisation in which, he argues, similar economic factors persisted to those which preceded the development of modern capitalism in European countries and yet did not result in countries like India or China developing modern capitalism. (Weber, Introduction to TPESC, 1930).

In his discussion, Weber details a number of connections between the persistence of Protestant values and the development of modern capitalism. Many centres of commercial activity – France, Germany, England, Scotland and Switzerland - evinced intense economic development, just as Protestantism was taking hold of Western Europe. (Morrison, 1995). In modern Europe (Weber wrote TPESC between 1902 and 1903), there was a correlation between religious affiliation and social stratification. Business leaders, owners of capital and highly skilled labourers were overwhelmingly Protestant. The relative dearth of Catholics involved in economic activity in Germany, for example, bucked the usual trend in which minorities are compelled by simple virtue of their marginalisation and oppression, to seek recognition in key industries and to excel even where they can receive no recognition from the State. (Weber, TPESC, chapter 1, 1930). Hence, the ensuing discussion.

The "spirit of capitalism"


The “spirit of capitalism” embodies three demands: 1) devotion to amassing wealth beyond personal needs, 2) commitment to unrelieved toil coupled with self-denial and 3) avoidance of use of wealth for personal enjoyment. (Morrison, 1995). Now, as Weber makes clear, this set of attitudes does not actually persist in modern capitalism. (Weber, TPESC, chapter 1, 1930). It is nevertheless the set of attitudes which eventuated in the development of modern capitalism. Weber adumbrates this “spirit” first by referring to the writings of Benjamin Franklin, a millionaire and self-help guru, specifically to a set of maxims to be found in his Necessary Hints to Those That Would Be Rich. Those hints include: 1) Time is money, 2) Credit is money, 3) Money is of the prolific, generating nature, 4) The good paymaster is the Lord of another man’s purse and 5) Evince a hard-working nature and it will boost one’s stand with creditors. “Truly,” says Weber, “what is preached here is not merely a means of making one’s way in the world, but a particular ethic.” It has “the character of an ethically-coloured maxim for life”. (Weber, TPESC, chapter 2, 1930). In fact, Weber goes on to describe Franklin’s recommendations as “moral attitudes” which are merely “coloured with utilitarianism”. Weber thinks he is justified in making these allusions because Franklin’s own life story speaks of his Calvinistic upbringing, and when Franklin is asked why should “money be made out of men”, he replies with a bible quote: “Seest thou a man diligent in his business? He shall stand before kings.” Franklin, however, had repudiated his Calvinist past when he wrote his manual so it is not clear whether he is entitled to his conclusions in this respect. (Elton, 1963).

Another way in which Weber illustrates the “spirit of capitalism” is by making a distinction between what he calls traditional capitalism and modern capitalism. Traditional capitalism endured until the 19th Century, and was episodic, adventurist, speculative etc. It included war, trade, piracy, even tax-bargaining with a feudal king. Modern capitalism involved the rationalisation of the labour process, the reinvestment of profit, and sustained and regular enterprise. The key difference he points to for his argument, however, is the attitude to work and consumption. Paying workers a higher piece rate in traditional capitalism had the effect of reducing the amount of work done, since they could obtain the same amount of money for less work. In modern capitalism, it would increase production since workers could get more money by working faster. This, he says, is because man does not wish to earn more and more money “by nature”, preferring his accustomed lifestyle. Capitalism has to overcome some stubborn resistance to get people to think and behave as consumers. (Weber, TPESC, chapter 2, 1930).

The "Protestant ethic"


This is where asceticism or the “Protestant ethic” comes in. The first part of the ethic discussed by Weber is the Lutheran notion of the “calling”, in which worldly avocations were considered God created and therefore “fulfillable in a spirit of worship”. This notion was known to medieval writers, but according to Weber it allowed Protestants to see in their daily life a devotion to God’s work. (Elton, 1963). The effect of the Reformation, Weber claimed, was that “the moral emphasis on, and the religious sanction of, organised worldly labour in a calling was mightily increased”. (Weber, TPESC, chapter 3, 1930). This was not enough in itself, however. The second aspect of this asceticism, therefore, is what Weber calls “worldly asceticism” which he attached especially to Calvinism. Calvin had rebuked the Catholic Church for its tolerance of worldly pleasures and its permissive doctrine toward salvation (in which “good works” would be considered a sufficient condition to erase sin and allow admittance to heaven). He proposed the doctrine of predestination in which: 1) God divides humanity into the ‘saved’ and the ‘damned’, 2) no believer can know his fate until it is revealed to her on death, 3) nothing can be done to relieve, or forgive, or reverse the decree, 4) God has abandoned all but the elect – Christ died only for them. To contain the resulting anxiety, Calvin placed two obligations on believers, the first being that they had an absolute duty to assume they were among the elect, the second being that they had to stave off doubt since this would be seen as a loss of faith. (Morrison, 1995; Weber, TPESC, chapter 4, 1930). As brotherly love could not be in the service of the flesh, it had to be expressed by work, in the service of God. This worldly grace served to allay the religious distress created by not knowing whether one was saved or damned. Unlike Catholic asceticism, there was no tendency to retreat from the world – this was asceticism in the world. (Weber, TPESC, chapter 4, 1930).

But it is through the work of Richard Baxter that Weber locates the link between the Puritan asceticism and the ‘spirit of capitalism’. A Presbyterian, he was inclined to religious moderation and dismayed by the more extreme doctrines of the fanatics. His book, the Christian Directory, was a compendium of Puritan ethics. Wealth, according to Baxter, is a moral danger – it invites idleness, relaxation, the temptations of the flesh. (Cock an eyebrow if you must, but some people still take this shit seriously.) A man should, to be certain of his state of grace, “do the works of him who has sent him, as long as it is yet day”. (Weber, TPESC, chapter 5, 1930). Labour was seen as a means both of fulfilling God’s will, and avoiding sin. Work had always been an approved ascetic device, but it was also now a condition of saving grace. There was also a tendency to regard the division of labour as providential, and also necessary to prevent idleness. And since God had his hand in all walks of life, if an opportunity for profit was placed before the Puritan, he was obliged to pursue it with a purpose. “To wish to be poor was, it was often argued, the same as wishing to be unhealthy … [asceticism] has the highest ethical appreciation of the sober, middle-class, self-made man.” Puritans also emphasised the virtues of formal law, insisting that Mosaic law retained its relevancy provided those trappings only relevant to Judaism were shorn - an important contribution to the development of capitalism. (Ibid).

There was a sense, however, in which the Puritan ethic was bound to disintegrate under the weight of its own creation. Weber cites John Wesley: “[R]eligion must necessarily produce both industry and frugality, and these cannot but produce riches. But as riches increase, so will pride, anger, and love of the world in all its branches … we must exhort all Christians to gain all they can, and save all they can; that is, in effect, to grow rich.” Or, as Weber notes, “the full economic effect of those great religious movements … generally came only after the peak of the purely religious enthusiasm was past.” (Weber, TPESC, chapter 5, 1930).

How accurate?


This is the trajectory of the “elective affinity” which was finally to result in the rise of modern capitalism. How accurate is this picture? Weber himself insisted that he was not arguing that capitalism “could only have arisen as the result of certain effects of the Reformation … On the contrary, we only wish to ascertain whether and to what extent religious forces have taken part in the qualitative formation and the quantitative expansion of this spirit in the world.” (Ibid). Indeed, Weber was positing his thesis of a “spirit of capitalism” as an “ideal-type”. Ideal-types, in the Weberian lexicon, are “logically and formally precise statements of possible relationships” which can then be tested for coherence and empirical validity. Weber’s argument was that within the setting of Western Europe in that historical epoch, and only within that setting, “the contribution of the Protestant ethic was indispensable to the rise of capitalism … In that sense only can the Protestant ethic be regarded as the cause of the rise of capitalism.” (Philip Abrams, Historical Sociology). Is even this, relatively weak, thesis compatible with the facts? There are some reasons to doubt this. For one thing, capitalism was well-developed in the south of Italy and Germany before Luther’s emergence as a reformer. And it subsequently developed without impediment in Catholic France, until the Thirty Years War. Anglican Britain and Catholic Belgium industrialised before more notable Protestant countries. (GR Elton, The Reformation, 1963). Moreover, as Maxime Rodinson has argued, it is possible to interpret the absence of capitalism in “Oriental” countries in a different and perhaps more pertinent light. After all, it wasn’t merely the Orient which failed to develop, it was also the rest of Asia and Africa – and this stagnation was confluent with the colonial expansion of Europe. It could be argued that the uniqueness of the West essentially comes down to its getting there first, and being able to subjugate the Rest, politically and economically. (Nazih Ayubi, Political Islam: Religion and Politics in the Arab World). And it was not really the petit-bourgeoisie and self-made men who were the agents of capitalism, as Weber supposes. A critical condition for the expansion of markets was the “enclosures” of land, in which peasants were thrown off the land so that it could be converted to pasture so as to sell sheep-wool. Many of those thrown off the land were forced to get jobs and accept wages in money, which made mass production sensible. In other words, the noble landlords and magnates, whose values were decidedly not those of Puritan asceticism, were in the vanguard of capitalism. (Sami Zubaida). What remains, perhaps, is that there is some connection between the rise of capitalism and the Reformation. It is not clear that it is a causal relationship and, if it is, in which direction the causality flows.

One more thing. Weber witnessed a confluence between hard work and Protestant values. He wasn't around to see the current President of the United States scamper about his ranch with his recently deceased mutt looking for doodle-bugs.

7:27:00 pm | Permalink | Comments thread | | Print | Digg | del.icio.us | reddit | StumbleUpon | diigo it Tweet| Share| Flattr this

Search via Google

Info

Richard Seymour

Richard Seymour's Wiki

Richard Seymour: information and contact

Richard Seymour's agent

RSS

Twitter

Tumblr

Pinterest

Academia

Storify

Donate

corbyn_9781784785314-max_221-32100507bd25b752de8c389f93cd0bb4

Against Austerity cover

Subscription options

Flattr this

Recent Comments

Powered by Disqus

Recent Posts

Subscribe to Lenin's Tomb
Email:

Lenosphere

Archives

September 2001

June 2003

July 2003

August 2003

September 2003

October 2003

November 2003

December 2003

January 2004

February 2004

March 2004

April 2004

May 2004

June 2004

July 2004

August 2004

September 2004

October 2004

November 2004

December 2004

January 2005

February 2005

March 2005

April 2005

May 2005

June 2005

July 2005

August 2005

September 2005

October 2005

November 2005

December 2005

January 2006

February 2006

March 2006

April 2006

May 2006

June 2006

July 2006

August 2006

September 2006

October 2006

November 2006

December 2006

January 2007

February 2007

March 2007

April 2007

May 2007

June 2007

July 2007

August 2007

September 2007

October 2007

November 2007

December 2007

January 2008

February 2008

March 2008

April 2008

May 2008

June 2008

July 2008

August 2008

September 2008

October 2008

November 2008

December 2008

January 2009

February 2009

March 2009

April 2009

May 2009

June 2009

July 2009

August 2009

September 2009

October 2009

November 2009

December 2009

January 2010

February 2010

March 2010

April 2010

May 2010

June 2010

July 2010

August 2010

September 2010

October 2010

November 2010

December 2010

January 2011

February 2011

March 2011

April 2011

May 2011

June 2011

July 2011

August 2011

September 2011

October 2011

November 2011

December 2011

January 2012

February 2012

March 2012

April 2012

May 2012

June 2012

July 2012

August 2012

September 2012

October 2012

November 2012

December 2012

January 2013

February 2013

March 2013

April 2013

May 2013

June 2013

July 2013

August 2013

September 2013

October 2013

November 2013

December 2013

January 2014

February 2014

March 2014

April 2014

May 2014

June 2014

July 2014

August 2014

September 2014

October 2014

November 2014

December 2014

January 2015

February 2015

March 2015

April 2015

May 2015

June 2015

July 2015

August 2015

September 2015

October 2015

December 2015

March 2016

April 2016

May 2016

June 2016

July 2016

August 2016

September 2016

October 2016

November 2016

December 2016

January 2017

February 2017

March 2017

April 2017

May 2017

June 2017

July 2017

August 2017

Dossiers

Hurricane Katrina Dossier

Suicide Bombing Dossier

Iraqi Resistance Dossier

Haiti Dossier

Christopher Hitchens Dossier

Organic Intellectuals

Michael Rosen

Left Flank

Necessary Agitation

China Miéville

Je Est Un Autre

Verso

Doug Henwood

Michael Lavalette

Entschindet und Vergeht

The Mustard Seed

Solomon's Minefield

3arabawy

Sursock

Left Now

Le Poireau Rouge

Complex System of Pipes

Le Colonel Chabert [see archives]

K-Punk

Faithful to the Line

Jews Sans Frontieres

Institute for Conjunctural Research

The Proles

Infinite Thought

Critical Montages

A Gauche

Histologion

Wat Tyler

Ken McLeod

Unrepentant Marxist

John Molyneux

Rastî

Obsolete

Bureau of Counterpropaganda

Prisoner of Starvation

Kotaji

Through The Scary Door

Historical Materialism

1820

General, Your Tank is a Powerful Vehicle

Fruits of our Labour

Left I on the News

Organized Rage

Another Green World

Climate and Capitalism

The View From Steeltown

Long Sunday

Anti-dialectics

Empire Watch [archives]

Killing Time [archives]

Ob Fusc [archives]

Apostate Windbag [archives]

Alphonse [archives]

Dead Men Left [dead, man left]

Bat [archives]

Bionic Octopus [archives]

Keeping the Rabble in Line [archives]

Cliffism [archives]

Antiwar

Antiwar.com

Antiwar.blog

Osama Saeed

Dahr Jamail

Angry Arab

Desert Peace

Abu Aardvark

Juan Cole

Baghdad Burning

Collective Lounge

Iraqi Democrats Against the Occupation

Unfair Witness [archive]

Iraq Occupation & Resistance Report [archive]

Socialism

Socialist Workers Party

Socialist Aotearoa

Globalise Resistance

Red Pepper

Marxists

New Left Review

Socialist Review

Socialist Worker

World Socialist Website

Left Turn

Noam Chomsky

South Africa Keep Left

Monthly Review

Morning Star

Radical Philosophy

Blogger
blog comments powered by Disqus